Европейская денежная система
| Категория реферата: Рефераты по экономике
| Теги реферата: решебники за 7 класс, доклад на тему
| Добавил(а) на сайт: Колганов.
Предыдущая страница реферата | 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 | Следующая страница реферата
ESCB's accountability to the public at large.
The realisation that achievement of an optimal, non-inflationary
macroeconomic outcome may founder on the private sector's distrust has been
central to the monetary policy debate of the nineteen-eighties and
'nineties. The search for answers to the questions raised by this debate
has spawned an enormous economic literature. The keywords "time
inconsistency" and "credibility" draw forth an almost unmanageable flood of
publications that have appeared in the wake of the pioneering contributions
of Kydland / Prescott and Barro / Gordon.
The need to establish a credible and consistent monetary strategy in the face of the well-known time inconsistency problem faced by policy makers - the dilemma highlighted by this economic literature - is especially important for the ESCB at the outset of Monetary Union. As a brand new institution, the ESCB will have no track record of its own.
Building its reputation, and the associated credibility of monetary
policy, is vital. But the process of doing so is complicated by the
relatively high level of uncertainty surrounding the transition to Monetary
Union itself. The transition to Stage Three is a unique event, and will
create unique opportunities for many - but it will also create some unique
problems for monetary policy makers. At the ECB, we are addressing these
problems and are confident that the risks can be managed successfully. Many
of the difficulties we face will be overcome through our own efforts over
the coming months.
Among these problems are the difficulties involved in creating a comprehensive and accurate database of euro area-wide statistics. Running a single monetary policy for the euro area requires timely, reliable and accurate euro area data. In some cases, the euro area statistics simply did not exist until quite recently. In others, the statistics are based on new concepts, and the properties of the data series are not yet well known. The long runs of high quality back-data required for empirical economic analysis may be unavailable. Those that do exist are likely to have been constructed using some degree of estimation and judgement, possibly rendering the econometric results produced with them questionable.
Furthermore, the regime shift associated with the adoption of the single monetary policy may change the way expectations are formed in the euro area, and thereby alter forward-looking economic behaviour. Monetary policy's effects on consumption, investment, and wage bargaining - and therefore the whole transmission mechanism of monetary policy to developments in the price level - would be among the important economic relationships to be affected in this way.
This may be no bad thing. Indeed, using the regime shift implied by the transition to Stage Three to change both public and private sector behaviour in favourable directions may be one of the largest gains that the euro area can extract from Monetary Union. Nevertheless, these changes are likely to complicate the implementation of certain important elements of a monetary strategy, at least in the short term, as past relationships between macroeconomic variables may break down. What is good for the euro area economy as a whole may create some practical problems for the ESCB.
One example of this so-called 'Lucas critique' phenomenon is the impact of current, very low rates of inflation on private behaviour. For many countries participating in Monetary Union, there is simply no - or only very recent - experience of how the private sector will behave in an environment of sustained and credible low inflation. Instability in past relationships may result, should behaviour change in this new, low inflation environment. I have already argued that these structural changes will benefit Europe's citizens - price stability will allow markets to work more efficiently, thereby raising growth, and improving employment prospects. But these changes may also complicate the ESCB's assessment of economic and financial conditions.
These uncertainties - arising directly from the transition to Stage
Three itself - are both compounded by, and inter-related with, the broader
economic context in which Monetary Union will be established. The
increasing internationalisation of the global economy, and the current
rapid pace of technological change, have affected all sectors of the
economy, and the banking and financial systems in particular. For example, at present there are many, inter-related innovations in the payments
system, such as:
* the introduction of TARGET (directly related to EMU itself);
* greater technological sophistication of payments mechanisms, as use of computers and information technology becomes more widespread and advanced;
* the additional incentive for cash-less payments that may arise from the fact that for some time to come - approximately three years - the new euro-denominated notes and coin will not come into circulation. In particular, narrow monetary aggregates might be affected by this development; and,
* increased competition among banks and settlements systems, arising from globalisation and the breakdown of barriers between previously segmented national markets, which may drive down the margins and fees charged to customers.
At the ESCB we will need to keep abreast of these developments, both for their immediate impact on one of our "basic tasks" - promoting the smooth operation of the payments system - and because of their broader implications for the euro area economy. Reducing transactions costs in the way I just described will benefit European consumers and producers - but it may also change the indicator properties of monetary, financial and economic variables that national central banks have looked to as guides for monetary policy in the past.
Finally, in Monetary Union there will be some heterogeneity across
countries within the euro area. Europe's diversity is one of its greatest
assets. But this diversity is greater than is typically the case between
different regions in the same country using a single currency.
Nevertheless, the ECB Governing Council will have to concentrate on
monetary and economic developments in the euro area as a whole when
discussing and taking monetary policy decisions.
How should a monetary policy strategy be selected in this - for
monetary policy makers, at least - potentially difficult environment? The
EMI outlined a number of 'guiding principles' for the selection of a
monetary strategy by the ESCB. Foremost amongst these was the principle of
'effectiveness'. The best monetary policy strategy for the ESCB is the one
which best signals a credible and realistic commitment to, and ensures
achievement of, the primary objective of price stability.
For many commentators, this criterion points unambiguously in the
direction of so-called 'direct inflation targeting'. If monetary strategies
are to be judged according to how well they achieve price stability, defined as a low rate of measured inflation, then advocates of inflation
targets argue an optimal strategy would surely target this low inflation
rate directly. These commentators would place explicit quantitative targets
for inflation itself at the centre of the ESCB's monetary policy strategy.
Their approach has been strongly endorsed in some academic and central
banking circles.
But, in the current circumstances, a pure 'direct inflation targeting' strategy is too simplistic for the ESCB, and possibly even mis- conceived. The ESCB well understands the primacy of price developments and price stability for monetary policy making. Indeed, the Treaty's mandate is unambiguous in this respect. We will signal our intentions on this dimension very clearly by making a transparent public announcement of our definition of price stability. The current low level of long-term nominal interest rates in the euro area suggests that the financial markets, at least, understand and believe the over-riding priority that we attach to achieving price stability.
Regarding strategy, our choice therefore need not be governed solely by a desire to signal our intent to maintain price stability. This has already been well-established - by the Treaty, and by the success of the convergence process in reducing inflation in Europe to its current low level. Rather than signalling our intent, the strategy must constitute a practical guide that ensures monetary policy is effective in achieving the goal we have been set.
In this respect, there are considerable problems with using inflation itself as the direct target within the ESCB's overall strategy. Because of the well-known lags in the transmission mechanism of monetary policy to the economy in general, and the price level in particular, it is impossible for a central bank to control inflation directly. Therefore, 'inflation targeting' in practice means 'inflation forecast targeting' where central banks set monetary policy to keep their best forecast of inflation at the target level deemed consistent with price stability.
But recognition of this need for forecasts in an inflation targeting strategy immediately raises practical difficulties. In the uncertain environment likely to exist at the outset of Monetary Union, forecasting inflation will be very difficult, not least for the conceptual, empirical and practical reasons I outlined a moment ago. Forecasting models estimated using historic data may not offer a reliable guide to the behaviour of the euro area economy under Monetary Union. Forecast uncertainty is likely to be relatively large, possibly rendering the whole inflation targeting strategy ineffective.
To address these uncertainties, a large element of judgement would have to be introduced into the forecasting process, in order to allow for the regime shifts and structural and institutional changes that are a seemingly inevitable consequence of EMU. Simply relying on historic relationships to forecast future developments is unlikely to prove accurate or effective. While introducing judgmental adjustments into forecasts in these circumstances would be both appropriate and necessary, such adjustments are likely to compromise the transparency of the inflation forecasts and, thus, of any inflation targeting strategy. Using judgement may prevent outside observers from readily assessing the reliability and robustness of the inflation forecasting procedures used by the ESCB.
I see a distinct bias in the academic discussion of the comparative
advantages of inflation targeting and monetary targeting. With good reason, many arguments are presented against the ESCB adopting a monetary target.
But proponents of inflation targeting seem to forget that, in the current
context, most of these arguments could also be used against inflation
targeting. Above all, I have not seen any attempt thus far - even if only a
tentative one - to explain how the ESCB should deal with the specific
difficulties involved in making an inflation forecast at the outset of
Monetary Union that could be used as the centrepiece of an inflation
targeting strategy.
In many respects, a strategy giving a prominent role to monetary
aggregates has considerable advantages over direct inflation targeting.
Monetary aggregates are published. They are clearly not subject to various
kinds of 'judgmental manipulation' by policy makers or central bank staff
that might be possible with inflation forecasts. To the extent that policy
makers wish to depart from the signals offered by monetary growth because
of 'special factors' or 'distortions' to the data - including those
distortions arising from the transition to Monetary Union itself - they
will have to do so in a public, clear and transparent manner.
Moreover, a strategy that assigns a prominent role to the monetary aggregates emphasises the responsibility of the ESCB for the monetary impulses to inflation, which a central bank can control more readily than inflation itself. These monetary impulses are the most important determinants of inflation in the medium term, while various other factors, such as terms of trade or indirect tax shocks, may influence the price level over shorter horizons.
In the light of these considerations, it was agreed at the EMI that, regardless of the final choice of the monetary policy strategy, monetary aggregates would be accorded a prominent role in the overall monetary framework adopted by the ESCB.
However, the EMI also noted that certain technical pre-conditions would have to be met before this 'prominent role' could be translated into an explicit, publicly announced monetary target, guideline, benchmark or monitoring range. Specifically, such targets or ranges would only be meaningful guides to monetary policy if the relationship between money and prices - as encapsulated in a 'demand for money' equation - was expected to remain sufficiently stable.
In this regard, several existing empirical studies point towards the
stability of the demand for euro area-wide monetary aggregates. However, these studies are necessarily only preliminary. The reliability of these
results in the face of the uncertainties raised by the transition to Stage
Three is unknown. Future shifts in the velocity of money are certainly
possible - perhaps even likely. They cannot be predicted with certainty.
Moreover, it is not clear whether those aggregates that have the best
results in terms of stability are sufficiently controllable in the short-
term with the policy instruments available to the ESCB. In these
circumstances, relying on a pure strategy of strict monetary targeting is
simply too risky.
Against this background, the ESCB will have to design a monetary policy strategy of its own. The chosen strategy will show as much as possible continuity with the successful strategies that participating NCBs conducted in the Stage Two. At the same time the ESCB's strategy will take into account to the extent needed the unique situation created by the introduction of the euro.
4. The new monetary policy instruments and procedures for the euro area
Having a well-designed monetary strategy is vital. But we must also be able to implement it successfully at an operational level. What instruments are available to implement this strategy?
The ECB will have a complete set of monetary policy instruments at its disposal. These instruments have been selected on the basis of their efficiency for transmitting monetary policy and their neutrality across market participants.
Three types of instruments are available to the ESCB: open market operations, standing facilities and a minimum reserve system. I will briefly present these instruments in the remainder of my speech.
4.1 Open market operations
Open market operations include, first, a weekly main refinancing operation, which will take the form of a reverse repurchase transaction with a maturity of two weeks. The main refinancing operation will be based on a tender procedure. The tender may be a fixed rate tender, with counterparties bidding amounts, or a floating rate tender, where counterparties propose bids including both amounts and interest rates.
Second, there is the monthly longer term refinancing operation, which has a maturity of three months and will always take the form of an interest rate tender. This is because the ECB will avoid signalling its monetary policy stance through these particular operations.
The ECB will also conduct fine-tuning operations, through the
national central banks of the euro area or, in exceptional circumstances, on its own account. Fine tuning operations will be conducted whenever
liquidity or money market conditions warrant. Fine tuning operations may
take the form of reverse repurchase transactions (that is, the same type of
transaction as that used in the main refinancing and the longer term
refinancing operations, but with no pre-set start date nor a pre-set
maturity), foreign exchange swaps or the taking of fixed-term deposits.
Fine tuning operations in the form of reverse repurchase operations may be
executed either through quick tenders or bilaterally. In both cases, these
operations will involve a limited set of eligible counterparties that have
an appropriate track record of activity in the money market. The other
types of fine tuning operations will also be executed with a limited number
of eligible counterparties, which will be selected ex ante by the ECB. In
some countries, there will be a rotation scheme, which will aim at giving
the opportunity to all eligible fine tuning counterparties to participate
in fine tuning operations.
Finally, open market operations may also be conducted whenever structural reasons, such as the longer-term evolution of liquidity profiles, warrant it. These so-called structural operations may take the form of outright purchases or sales of securities or the issuance of debt certificates by the ECB.
4.2 Standing facilities
The ECB will operate two overnight standing facilities, which will be
available to all credit institutions at national central banks of the euro
area, provided that, when using the marginal lending facility, they have
sufficient collateral. The rate of the marginal lending facility will
constitute the upper bound of collateralised overnight money market rates.
The deposit facility will be remunerated at a rate that will constitute the
lower bound of overnight money market rates.
When using the marginal lending facility, or, for that matter, when
entering in liquidity-providing open market operations in the form of
reverse transactions, counterparties have to post assets with their
national central bank (or the ECB in the exceptional case when the ECB
conducts fine tuning operations on its own account). These assets are meant
to act as guarantees for credits received from the European System of
Central Banks. A list of eligible assets has been drawn up for this
purpose. The list comprises a wide variety of assets and has two sub-sets.
First, the so-called tier one assets, which are selected by the ECB
according to uniform criteria relating to their credit standing in the
whole euro area. Second, the so-called tier two assets, which have been
selected by the ECB because they are of particular importance for certain
national banking systems of the euro area, in order to promote a certain
degree of continuity at the start of the Stage Three of EMU. Two principles
of equal treatment are applied, however. First, the credit standing of tier
two assets is as high as that of tier one assets. Second, both tier one and
tier two assets may be used by any credit institution in the euro area, irrespective of its location.
In addition, a set of risk control measures has been elaborated to ensure that, for any counterparty, the amount of assets provided is always sufficient. Risk control measures cover the assets' price and credit risks, taking account of the asset type, its characteristics and the maturity of the transaction. The ECB's risk control measures have been elaborated with careful attention to the best market practices in this area. They include the deduction of haircuts from the assets and the imposition of initial margins to the credit amount. Another feature of the risk control framework is the regular revaluations of the assets, which will, in most cases, take place daily and may trigger margin calls, most often to be settled through delivery of additional assets.
4.3 Minimum reserve system
The ECB will also apply a minimum reserve system to credit
institutions of the euro area. Two main monetary policy objectives have
been assigned to the minimum reserve system. The first objective is to
stabilise money market interest rates through the averaging mechanism, whereby the fulfilment of minimum reserve requirements is based on average
reserve holdings over monthly periods of time. During the maintenance
period, this allows the banking system to absorb liquidity shocks. The
reduced volatility of money market rates will reduce the need for frequent
fine tuning operations, which will mean that markets are less distorted by
central bank interventions than they would otherwise be. The second
objective of the minimum reserve system is to enlarge the demand for
central bank money, so as to enlarge the liquidity deficit of the banking
system vis-а-vis the ESCB. This will safeguard the role of the European
System of Central Banks as a provider of liquidity to the banking system.
Reserve requirements will be calculated by applying a reserve ratio
of 1.5% to 2.5% to the deposits, debt securities and money market paper
issued by credit institutions, except for residual maturities above two
years. Although repurchase agreements are included in the reserve base, they will be subject to a zero reserve ratio. In 1999SCHD-MAY.DOCf[pic]1 T-
-#"+ !-+ 1999PROT10.DOCfter-bank liabilities and liabilities vis-а-vis
the ESCB will not be subject to reserve requirements. An allowance of the
order of E 100,000 will be deducted from reserve requirements, so that
credit institutions with a small reserve base will not have to hold minimum
reserves.
Reserve holdings will be remunerated up to the required reserve level, at the rate of the main refinancing operation (as averaged over a month). It may be argued that a less than full remuneration of minimum reserves would increase the interest rate elasticity of central bank money demand. This notwithstanding, the ECB has decided in favour of a full remuneration of minimum reserves in view of the distortion to efficient markets that a less than full remuneration would have implied. As a result of the full remuneration of minimum reserves, the European Central Bank has also decided not to exempt any credit institution from the minimum reserve system.
4.4 Procedures
The ECB will have many counterparties and be subject to close public scrutiny. It has therefore set up procedures for informing its counterparties and the public about its monetary policy instruments in a robust and transparent manner.
The ECB will inform its counterparties and the public through a document detailing its monetary policy instruments and procedures and through the regular publication of various materials on its Internet site.
General Documentation
Рекомендуем скачать другие рефераты по теме: ценные бумаги реферат, реферат по физкультуре.
Категории:
Предыдущая страница реферата | 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 | Следующая страница реферата